• <tr id="yyy80"></tr>
  • <sup id="yyy80"></sup>
  • <tfoot id="yyy80"><noscript id="yyy80"></noscript></tfoot>
  • 99热精品在线国产_美女午夜性视频免费_国产精品国产高清国产av_av欧美777_自拍偷自拍亚洲精品老妇_亚洲熟女精品中文字幕_www日本黄色视频网_国产精品野战在线观看 ?

    Green nudging*

    2018-11-11 09:11:51NicolaoBoniniConstantinosHadjichristidisandMicheleGraffeo
    心理學報 2018年8期

    Nicolao Bonini, Constantinos Hadjichristidis,2 and Michele Graffeo

    (1 Department of Economics and Management, University of Trento, Italy)

    (2 Centre for Decision Research, Leeds University Business School, University of Leeds, UK)

    Abstract: Our current lifestyle is not sustainable.One way to increase sustainability is by developing greener technologies.Another, complementary way, is by altering people’s attitudes, habits, and behaviors.Here we discuss six techniques that aim to gently push or nudge people towards more pro-environmental choices and behaviors.These techniques range from ones that can be applied from a distance, e.g., techniques which could inform the construction of communication messages, to ones that involve changes in the context where the choice takes place.Therefore, the present review can be of interest to practitioners such as marketers,policymakers, and consumer representatives.For each technique, we discuss its theorized cognitive and/or emotional underpinnings.Furthermore, we identify gaps in the literature and ways in which future research could fill these gaps.

    Key words decision-making; nudging; pro-environmental decisions; context effects

    Public Policy and Behavioral Decision Research

    In modern societies the resolution of public problems,which are often complex, frequently relies on the active involvement of citizens.Citizen involvement can take many forms.In developed countries, for example, a number of public goods are supplied privately.Philanthropic organizations, churches and other religious associations, labor unions, political parties, health research campaigns, private radio and television channels, all depend on a substantial way on voluntary monetary contributions (see Oppenheimer & Olivola, 2010, for a review of experimental studies on charity giving).

    Apart from monetary contributions, citizens can help resolve public problems more actively by dedicating part of their free time to carrying out volunteer work.In Italy, for instance, the Italian institute of socioeconomic studies (CENSIS) estimates that approximately one-eighth of Italian citizens devote more than one-third of their free time doing volunteer work for a non-profit organization.Yet another form of citizen involvement is through political activism.For example, citizens could sign a petition or cast a vote in a referendum regarding a specific initiative.Finally, citizens can also aid in the resolution of public problems by changing their attitudes, lifestyles, behaviors and habits.Consider,for example, the small habitual actions citizens can perform to combat the diffusion of the Asian tiger mosquito, to recycle waste, or to combat environmental pollution.

    This last form of citizen involvement, changing citizens’ behavior, can provide one of the most effective means of promoting a public good when viewed from a cost-benefit standpoint.Here we will discuss of a specific approach—

    nudging

    —that offers a promising alternative way to public policy-making based on economic incentives that aim to either punish unwanted behavior (by putting in place administrative sanctions, such as fines, taxes, and other suppressive mechanisms) or promote desirable behaviors (e.g.by providing contributions towards the acquisition of more efficient house appliances such as washing machines).Indeed,

    nudging

    is one of the most popular approaches aiming to alter citizens’behaviors (for discussions see Bhargava &Loewenstein, 2015; Halpern, 2015; Sunstein, 2014).Its intellectual origins can be traced to Thaler and Sunstein (2003) and Camerer et al., 2003.

    To nudge

    someone can be translated as to prod someone into action, to push gently, especially with the elbow.The main advantage of

    nudging

    over other techniques is that it alters behavior by acting on the intuitive system of the decision-maker; it is not based on suppressive mechanisms or on the promotion of an analytic/reflective mode of thinking (for an introduction to dual-system approaches of judgment and decision-making, see Kahneman, 2011).Furthermore, its application frequently requires minimal costs for the public administration.As Thaler and Sunstein (2008) note: nudging refers to“any aspect of the choice architecture that alters people’s behavior in a predictable way without forbidding any options or significantly changing their economic incentives” (p.6).In the words of the Nobel Laureate Daniel Kahneman, nudging yields“medium-sized gains by nano-sized investments” (see Bhargava & Loewenstein, 2015, p.397).

    In the present review we discuss six nudges that aim to promote pro-environmental choices and behaviors.We do not present an exhaustive list, and do not offer a new theoretical foundation for the nudging approach.Rather, our aim is to discuss nudges that cover the entire decision process: from the initial intelligence gathering to the actual choice.For example, we discuss nudges that concern the design of a distant communication where the citizen is first informed about the public good/action (e.g.information about the opportunity cost of a green action) but also nudges that pertain to the design of the actual choice context where the citizen is asked to make a decision (e.g.ambient smell and choice menu display).Each nudge relates to a specific psychological mechanism, which we fully describe and comment.We review papers that, in our judgment,outline the most effective psychological mechanisms to induce pro-environmental decisions.By providing examples of nudges that cover many aspects of the decision process, the present review can be of relevance to practitioners such as marketers,policymakers and consumer representatives.

    Referent points and evoked sets

    The first nudge we will discuss can be utilized to construct effective communication strategies, such as when informing citizens about the costs and benefits of a particular behavior.Its efficacy is based on the fact that people, when they are asked to evaluate a target public good, are influenced by comparison standards (points of reference), which can be altered,either explicitly or implicitly, through a communication message (the importance of reference points has been highlighted in

    prospect theory

    , Kahneman & Tversky,1979).

    For example, one way of altering the comparison standards when evaluating a certain public good involves explicitly stating alternative uses of money or, more technically, stating the opportunity costs.For example, we can ask a person to contribute money to an intervention (reforestation) related to a public good (e.g.a certain park).At the same time, in the message we could indicate alternative uses of the suggested monetary contribution for the public good.That is, we could state that instead of donating the money to support the target public good one could use it to buy an alternative product.

    Consider, for example, the work of Bonini, Biel,G?rling and Karlsson (2002, Study 1).A sample of Swedish citizens were asked to state their willingness to pay (WTP) to combat the acidification of Swedish lakes.In one condition (low opportunity cost), the participants were informed that instead of contributing for the public good they could spend the money (200 SEK [Swedish Krona]) to purchase an annual pass for the museum of the Goteborg Bank.In another condition (high opportunity cost), participants were instead informed that they could use the money to buy a concert ticket.The results show that in the high opportunity cost condition (concert ticket), the participants’ mean contribution towards the public good was 131 SEK, while in the low opportunity cost condition (museum pass) the mean contribution was significantly higher, 180 SEK.Evidently, the specific example used to highlight an alternative use of money — which is arbitrary — proved to be psychologically relevant as it influenced the contribution towards the target public good.The message of this research is clear: to promote monetary contributions towards pro-environmental causes the communication message could compare the requested contribution for the public good to a contribution for something that the participants perceive to be of lesser value.

    Standards of comparison can be evoked in many different ways.Apart from mentioning examples that emphasize the opportunity cost of a contribution, one could instead ask a person to recollect a positive or negative consumer experience.In this way, one could evoke either a positive or negative comparison standard.The role of episodic memory on people’s WTP for a public good was studied by Bonini et al.(2002, Study 2).The results showed that Swedish citizens were more WTP to clean up their country’s lakes when they had been previously asked to recall a negative consumer experience versus a positive consumer experience.Specifically, in the negative memory prime condition, participants were willing to contribute on average 185 SEK towards the public good, whereas in the positive memory prime condition, the average contribution dropped to 140 SEK.

    A third way of altering the comparison standards against which people are likely to compare the target public good is by presenting, together with the public good, one or more other public goods.In so doing, an individual is forced to consider the target public good in the context of the other public goods (which are not necessarily competing).The specific public goods that are presented simultaneously with the target public good, as we will see below, can sway people’s willingness to contribute toward it.

    In the pioneering studies of Daniel Kahneman and his collaborators (Kahneman & Ritov, 1994;Kahneman, Ritov, & Schkade, 1999; Ritov &Kahneman, 1997) it was demonstrated that individuals’evaluations of a public good are influenced by the evaluation context, and in particular by whether the public good is evaluated in isolation versus jointly with other public goods.For example, when a good concerning the protection of dolphins and another good concerning prevention of skin cancer for farmers where evaluated separately (separate evaluation),overall participants were relatively more WTP to save the dolphins than to protect farmers from skin cancer.However, when the two goods were evaluated simultaneously (joint evaluation), overall participants were more WTP for the farmer than the dolphin problem—revealing the exact opposite preference than that suggested by the separate evaluations.

    One interpretation of these findings is that the separate evaluation and the joint evaluation modes prompt different thinking processes.Specifically,when a public good is evaluated in isolation, people’s WTP may principally depend on the immediate affective reaction (integral affect) that the public good triggers (e.g., “I love dolphins”).However,when a public good is evaluated jointly with another,its evaluation is likely to also depend on other factors such as the pros and cons of contributing to this good versus to the other good that is mentioned (e.g., “it is not reasonable or ethical to pay more money to protect animals than to protect people”).

    These findings, and the associated theoretical accounts, carry practical implications for the design of public policy.For example, if one wishes to make citizens more likely to evaluate a public good affectively (this would be desirable, for instance,when a public good typically prompts a strong affective response), then it is preferable to avoid comparisons with other public goods, irrespective of whether these other goods are perceived to be comparatively lower or higher in importance.However, when the target public good is unlikely to trigger a strong emotional response, it might be better to present it together with other public goods that the majority of people consider to be of lesser importance.

    However, there exists an alternative interpretation of these findings.According to this interpretation, the differences between separate and joint evaluations arise because the comparison goods in the two evaluation contexts differ.When a single public good is presented, people

    spontaneously

    compare it to other public goods that belong to the

    same category

    (

    natural evoked set

    ).For instance, in the separate evaluation condition, citizens might compare the value of saving dolphins against the value of saving other endangered animal species, while they might compare the value of preventing skin cancer against the value of preventing other forms of cancer.Because dolphins are perceived to be relatively important in comparison to other endangered animals,while skin cancer is perceived to be relatively unimportant in comparison to other, more lethal,forms of cancer, the WTP for dolphins is higher than the WTP for farmers when these goods are evaluated separately.However, this natural comparative process is “blocked” in the joint evaluation condition in which both public goods are presented together.Here,the participants are forced to compare the two public goods, which they would not normally do in the separate evaluation condition, and this can alter their choices.For example, their choice may be influenced by a consideration of reasons to contribute for one good rather than for the other (see

    reason-based choice

    by Shafir, Simonson, & Tversky, 1993)Experimental results in support of this hypothesis have been obtained by Bonini, Ritov and Graffeo(2008).Bonini and colleagues (2008) reasoned that if people spontaneously compare a public good to other goods from the same category (spontaneously evoked set), then evaluating a target good jointly with either a low-importance or high-importance public good from

    the same category

    should leave judgments for the target good unaffected.However, evaluating a target good jointly with either a low-importance or high-importance public good from

    a different category

    should increase judgments for the target good in the former instance while decrease them in the latter.In support of their predictions, Bonini and colleagues found that 38% of the participating Israeli interviewees were willing to financially support target problems, such as “conservation of early twentieth-century buildings in Hanevi’m Street in Jerusalem” and “expanding the activities of the scout movement,” in the context of relatively lowimportance referent problems from the

    same category

    ,while 34% in the context of relatively highimportance referent problems from the

    same category

    .However, when the referent problems belonged to a

    different category

    , the percentage increased to 40%when the referent problems were relatively lowimportance, and dropped drastically to 19% when they were relatively high-importance.The same pattern of findings was found when people were asked instead about whether they would sign a local petition,that is, whether they would support a public action politically.

    The results presented in this section carry implications for the construction of communication strategies.All else being equal, to achieve a high contribution for a target public good, one should present it jointly with less important goods from a different category.Future studies could investigate whether presenting information about opportunity costs, alternative public goods, or both, is more effective in increasing people’s willingness to support a target public good through monetary or other means.

    The communication of a social norm

    The second nudge that we will discuss—the communication of a social norm—can also assist in developing effective communication strategies.This strategy involves informing citizens about what the majority of other people do in a certain situation (e.g.,“most people are willing to give a small contribution to help reforestation”; “nine out of ten clients which stayed in this hotel room reused their towel”).Social psychologists refer to such messages as messages stating a

    social norm

    .Cialdini and Trost (1998)define social norms as the rules that are accepted by a group, and which have the capacity to guide and constrain people’s behavior.Just as the violation of law is punished, the violation of social norms is also punished.However, the type of punishment differs.Social norm violation is not punished by the law authorities but rather by one’s peers.The sanctions usually involve various forms of ostracism, that is,the marginalization of a person from a group.It is noteworthy to mention that social norms can be used(either consciously or unconsciously) to promote many types of behaviors ranging from peaceful social interactions, law-abiding behaviors, to illegal actions(if most people do not pay taxes, then a person may be enticed not to pay taxes).Thus, the communication of social norms can cut both ways—it can promote both desirable and undesirable behaviors, and thus it should be used with caution.Cialdini and Trost (1998) sustain that the reason why social norms exist is because humans, through them, aim to achieve various objectives.Some norms aim to increase the efficacy of certain actions especially in contexts surrounded by ambiguous circumstances.In such contexts, people often observe others and consider their behaviors as a valuable source of information.Norms concerning what other people do are known as

    descriptive social norms

    .The impact of a descriptive social norm increases the more people follow that norm, because norm following is interpreted as evidence that the norm is adequate.Furthermore, it is more probable that a social norm will be followed if we perceive norm followers as similar to us rather than different—if a norm is adequate for such and such people that are similar to us, then it should also be adequate for us.

    Cialdini, Reno and Kallgren (1990) examined how descriptive social norms influence behaviors through experimental studies.These authors conducted experiments in various locations (e.g., playgrounds,parking lots, etc.).On alternate occasions they manipulated whether the location was clean or dirty.Their idea was that when people find themselves in a clean environment they may infer that the social norm is to keep the environment clean, given that other persons that have been in that environment did not litter.But when people find themselves in a dirty environment, they may infer that the social norm is to litter, given that other people have done so (see also the “broken windows” theory, Wilson & Kelling,1982; and Zimbardo, 1969).In one experiment, the participants (who were not aware that they were observed) found some advertisement flyers in their cars.These flyers were of the type that most people would throw away in the earliest occasion.The results show that participants behave in a way congruent to that indicated by the social descriptive norm:participants were more likely to throw the flyer on the ground when the environment (parking lot) was already littered, than when it was clean.

    Another human need is the need to acquire resources and social support in order to improve one’s quality of life.A particularly effective strategy to satisfy this need is the creation of social networks.One way in which people may seek other group members’ approval is by following the norms of the group.Cialdini and Trost (1998) called norms concerning what the majority of people believe that one

    should

    or

    should not

    do as

    injunctive social norms

    .Injunctive norm compliance is motivated by prizes and punishments that other people are ready to issue in response to our actions.

    For example, if one finds a wallet on the ground a common injunctive norm in many cultures/social groups is to return it to its lawful owner.This is the socially responsible thing to do, that is, the behavior which would gain approval by the group.In a fascinating study, Hornstein, Fisch and Holmes (1968)left wallets in the streets of New York, containing money, documents, and a note.The note appeared to be written by a passerby who found the wallet and left it in a prominent place so that its lawful owner could find it.In certain cases the note appeared to be written by a US citizen (an in-group member for most of the participants), whereas in other cases by a person that had recently immigrated to the US (an outgroup member for most of the participants).The proportion of people that made an effort to return the wallet was twice as high in the first case that in the second case.The authors interpreted this result as showing that injunctive norms, which normally have a general nature, vary in force depending on the similarity between the person that makes them explicit (e.g.the author of the note) and the person that must enforce them (e.g.the participant).The more similar these persons are, the more likely that the injunctive norm would be approved and respected.However, if these persons are dissimilar, as in the case of the immigrant who is perceived to be different and distant, the injunctive norm is perceived to be less important and is more often ignored.

    The use of a communication strategy based on social norms (descriptive or both descriptive and injunctive) to support a pro-environmental cause has been studied by Schultz et al.(2007).In the San Marcos community in California they performed a field experiment.Households in this community received normative feedback pertaining to how much energy they consumed in previous weeks along with information of how much, on average, other households in their neighborhood have consumed.The experimenters divided households into ones with above average consumption and ones with below average consumption.Half of the households in each condition received only descriptive feedback (e.g.,that they have consumed either above or below average), while the other half the descriptive feedback was supplemented by an appropriately valenced emoticon (either ? or ?).The main dependent measure was how much energy the households consumed in subsequent periods.

    The results showed that when participants received only descriptive feedback, the energy consumption in subsequent periods tended to move toward the norm.That is, households with above average energy consumption tended to consume relatively less than previously, and those with below average energy consumption tended to consume more than previously.Thus, in the latter case the normative feedback induced what is known as a

    boomerang effect

    .Importantly, the results showed that when the descriptive feedback was supplemented with an appropriately valenced emoticon, households with above average energy consumption tended to consume less, but critically households with below average consumption continued to consume less.Otherwise stated, the inclusion of the emoticon eliminated the

    boomerang effect

    .The message for policy makers is clear: for a message to be effective together with a descriptive norm it should also communicate clearly the behavior that is deemed acceptable by a social group (e.g., by means of an appropriately valenced emoticon).

    Studies have also shown that people’s behavior is not only influenced by descriptive and injunctive norms, but also by the specific manner in which the norms are communicated.For example, a social norm can be communicated in a generic/abstract way or in a more vivid way.More specifically, the communication may involve a dry statistic (“nine out of ten clients reuse their towel”; “your electricity consumption exceeds the mean consumption of your neighbors by 10%”), but could also be supplemented by vivid details about the citizens mentioned in the norm (e.g.,by providing a detailed description of them).

    Recently, Graffeo, Ritov, Bonini and Hadjichristidis(2015) examined whether a communication of a descriptive norm (e.g., your electricity consumption exceeds by 10% that of comparable others) is more effective when supplemented by information specifying who these “comparable others” are.The authors varied who the “comparable others” are following a 2 ×2 design.The first factor concerned whether the comparative others lived in the same neighborhood as the participants or in a different neighborhood, while the second whether or not additional details about their comparative others (their names and a photograph)were provided.The authors also included two control conditions: one in which no feedback was provided,and another where only statistical feedback was provided (feedback about the average household in their home country).The results showed that the condition associated with the highest willingness to reduce their electricity consumption was the one where the comparable others came from the same neighborhood as the participants but their members were not identified.(Perhaps giving further details about the comparable others increases the perceived dissimilarity between oneself and those others).Therefore, the results of this study suggest ways to further tweak how descriptive norms are presented to help promote even “greener” behaviors.

    The use of a foreign language

    The third nudge that we will discuss concerns the language in which a message is communicated and,specifically, whether this is a person’s mother tongue or a foreign language (i.e., a language that the person knows well but mostly though formal instruction or education).Recent studies have shown that communicating information in a foreign versus a native language can impact moral judgments (see Costa et al., 2014; Geipel, Hadjichristidis, & Surian,2015a, 2015b, 2016) and judgments of risk and benefit (see Hadjichristidis, Geipel, & Savadori,2015).More pertinently to the present purposes,research has also shown that foreign language use can also influence consumers’ response to advertising messages (Puntoni, de Langhe, & van Osselaer, 2009).The main explanation is that the use of a foreign language reduces emotionality and thus leads to judgments that are less swayed by affective considerations (see Caldwell-Harris, 2015;Hadjichristidis, Geipel, & Surian, 2017; Keysar,Hayakawa, & An, 2012; Puntoni et al., 2009; for recent reviews see Hayakawa, Costa, Foucart, &Keysar, 2016, and Costa, Vives, & Corey, 2017).

    Of particular interest to the present purposes is a study by Geipel, Hadjichristidis and Klesse (2018),which, extending on the work of Puntoni et al.(2009),investigated whether the use of a foreign language promotes higher intentions to consume certain sustainable products that people typically find just too disgusting to consume (see Rozin, Haddad,Nemeroff, & Slovic, 2015).Specifically, Geipel and colleagues investigated people’s willingness to consume recycled water, artificial meat, and insect-based food.In all three cases, the use of a foreign language promoted higher willingness to consume.Importantly, in a further study, the authors found that the use of a foreign language influenced consumers’ willingness to consume through attenuating feelings of disgust.

    Finally, these authors found that the use of foreign language can also sway behavior.In one of their studies, participants after being presented with a brief description of recycled water (either in a foreign or native language), were provided with a glass of“recycled water” from which they could drink as much or as little as they wished.The authors then measured how much “recycled water” each participant consumed.For participants who stated that they were thirsty at the beginning of the experiment, there was no effect of language.However, for participants that reported that they were not thirsty, foreign language promoted higher recycled water consumption.

    Given that we live in increasingly multicultural and multilingual societies, in which people are accustomed to receive communications in what is for them a foreign language (e.g., English), the suggestions relating to these findings are actionable (Teachman,Norton, & Spellman, 2015).Foreign language nudges should be particularly effective in promoting target public goods that typically prompt an aversive affective reaction, such as recycled water or insect-based food.However, it is noteworthy to mention that in certain cases foreign language communications—just as messages stating descriptive norms—may backfire.Consider, for example,affective advertisement that aims to deter undesirable behaviors such as the messages “Smoking kills” or“Smoking causes impotence” in cigarette packs.The use of a foreign language may reduce the impact of such messages (see Puntoni et al., 2009).Thus,foreign language use should be employed strategically.

    The “default” option

    A default option refers to the preselected option.It is the option that would be automatically followed unless a decision maker actively opposes it (e.g., by ticking “I do not wish that my information is passed to third parties” in an internet site).Default choices are taken on the basis of presumed or implied consent,rather than on the basis of explicit consent.Default choices are commonly used in legal contracts,technological environments, and other consumer environments.In technological environments, for example, several operating systems, software packages,and technological instruments have preselected defaults from the programmer/ constructor.For example, Windows 10 has Microsoft Edge as the default internet provider, and Bling as the default browser.Similarly, in the context of online acquisitions,certain main consumer goods (e.g., a train ticket, a personal loan) were by default bundled together with accessory goods (e.g., seat booking, an insurance policy).Although the client is allowed to change the default option (the client can opt-out from the seat booking or the insurance policy), few do so.Also for this reason, such commercial practices have been banned from the EU.

    The manipulation of the default choice is one of the most potent and frequently used nudges.It operates on the design of the choice architecture and,in particular, on how the alternatives are structured/organized.There exist various accounts as to why people tend to “select” a default option.First, people may not even notice that they had to make a choice.Second, people may notice this but assume that the default option is recommended by a competent authority (e.g., by the state).Third, actively making a decision involves costs in terms of money and time;going along with the default avoids such costs.Finally, it has been demonstrated that people prefer not to choose (

    omission bias

    ), accepting the consequences of this inertia, rather than assuming the responsibility to act (Ritov & Baron, 1992).The presumed source of the omission bias

    is that people judge more negatively undesirable outcomes that result from action (for which they are responsible)than ones that are the consequence of inaction.Thus,people may prefer to go along with the default to avoid the psychological cost associated with coming to terms with a (bad) action.The manipulation of the default choice has been studied in very diverse domains ranging from organ donation to the contribution toward pensions (see Thaler & Sunstein, 2008).More pertinent to the present purposes, this strategy has also proven effective in promoting environmental goods and, in particular, “green” electric tariffs which involve electricity deriving from renewable sources (for

    green defaults

    , see Pichert & Katsikopoulos, 2008)To get a glimpse of what it means to design the choice environment and how effective and easy it is to implement a default choice strategy, consider the change of the

    default

    settings on the printers in Rutgers University.Rutgers University changed the default setting from “single-sided” printing (persons who wanted “double-sided” printing could simply select that option) to “double-sided” printing (naturally,whomever wanted “single-sided” printing could simply change the default option).The results from the first semester after the change was implemented showed a saving of 7 million pages, or about 620 trees (Rutgers, 2017).An example of a dual strategy—default choice selection

    and

    economic incentive—concerns some policies about how to send clients invoices and receipts.In the USA, several banks, energy suppliers, and telephone companies, by default send bills in electronic format.Clients may request a hard copy of the bill but they have to

    specifically ask

    for this service and

    are charged

    for it[see

    La Note d’Analyse

    , Premiere Ministre, Republique Francaise, March 2011, n.216, p.4].

    The setting of the default option is a good example of “l(fā)ibertarian paternalism” (see Thaler &Sunstein, 2003).Although citizens are nudged, or gently pushed, towards a behavior which ultimately promotes the common good, they are free to act differently; they could opt-out from the default choice.Perhaps one exception is when citizens do not realize that they had the option to opt out from a default (e.g.,when one accepts the conditions of a long internet contract that includes several default options; it could be that the person does not even notice this, but just skips to the last page and clicks “agree”).

    Feedback

    Another way to nudge citizens towards greener choices involves giving them

    feedback

    in regards to the consequences of their actions (e.g., the amount of electricity they consume; how their consumption compares to relevant others; and so forth).Recall that the central theoretical idea behind nudging is that decisions are influenced by the context in which they are made (the assumption is that decisions are made here and now,

    hic et nunc

    ).The type of feedback

    one receives influences the choice context and, therefore,it may also affect the individuals’ choices and behaviors.

    One example of the efficacy of this nudge is described in Fischer’s review (Fischer, 2008).Specifically, Fischer describes the manner in which various types of feedback can promote a reduction in electric energy consumption.Fisher sustains that feedback influences consumers’ motivation to save electric energy because it indicates a problem (if consumers are not aware of their high electricity consumption, then why would they consider reducing it?) and what actions can help alleviate the problem (e.g., separate indicators for each electric appliance could help pinpoint the main sources of electric consumption).Fischer highlights several key factors for increasing the effectiveness of a feedback message.First,Fischer notes that a feedback is more effective when it immediately follows an action.Immediate feedback helps create a direct association between cause and effect, increasing consumers’ awareness about the costs of their consumption choices.Second, frequent and repeated feedback

    for a prolonged period of time can facilitate the creation of habits (e.g., the habit of switching off the lights when one leaves the room),which may have positive consequences.Third, the effectiveness of feedback also depends on how precise and specific they are.For example, a detailed analysis of energy costs per room, time of day, and single electric appliance, may help consumers to adopt more efficient strategies to reduce their energy consumption.An example of efficient feedback, which incorporates many of the key elements identified by Fischer, is provided by

    Ambient Orb

    , a light bulb produced by Southern California Edison that changes color depending on energy consumption (red when the consumption is very high, green when it is low/optimal).Thus,

    Ambient Orb

    provides an immediate, direct, and continuous feedback, in a context where consumers know what steps to take in order to save energy.Studies suggest that the adoption of this product has helped reduce energy consumption by 40% (see Thaler & Sunstein, 2008).An example of a green nudge technique that combines descriptive social norms and feedback has been tested through the electricity bills sent to citizens by the municipality of the city of Sacramento(

    The New York Times

    , 31 January, 2009).Starting at April 2008 around 35000 electricity users were extracted at random and received together with the traditional electricity bill a happy or sad face.The appearance of the happy or sad face depended on whether the user’s consumption compared favorably or unfavorably to the mean consumption of 100 families from the

    same

    neighbourhood that had a similar household size and utilized the

    same

    type of heating system.Following six months from this intervention, Alexandra Crawford, the spokesperson of the municipality of Sacramento, declared that the results of the intervention were very encouraging and that the intervention had a bigger impact than more traditional methods such as price incentives/reduction when buying energy efficient electric appliances and so forth.This study shows that an economic incentive alone is not sufficient to promote an initiative: the incentive should also be

    psychologically tempting

    .Furthermore, the study shows that non-economic incentives (such as, a social-affective feedback) can be effective in changing people’s behaviours.

    The use of social comparison (or competition)and the associated emotions this process triggers were successively employed by other municipal administrations of metropolitan areas, such as those of Chicago and Seattle.Recently, the use of social competition to promote “green” behaviors was implemented in Massachusetts from a non-profit organization with the help of a local television network.Specifically, the non-profit organization planned a competition which involved announcing the more virtuous neighbourhood in terms of energy consumption.In this case, just as in the case of the intervention by the municipality of Sacramento, the results were encouraging and were obtained at a low cost.

    Contextual priming

    Another technique used to nudge citizens concerns

    contextual priming

    , which involves intervening on the environment (

    atmospherics

    ) in which an individual has to make a choice.Nudging techniques based on contextual priming are congruent with the nudging philosophy, which holds that people construct their preferences online and that their preferences are influenced by characteristics of the environment in which they have to make a choice.There are many contextual characteristics one can intervene upon including ones that have a social character (e.g., characteristics that concern the interaction between vendor and client) and ones that could be characterized as physical (e.g., one can alter the lighting, odors, sounds, architectural spaces, and so forth).Frequently, such context alterations involve modifying certain “peripheral information,” that is,information that is not directly related to the product that is being judged (e.g., they are unrelated to qualitative or quantitative aspects such as the price of the good).

    Within the context of priming interventions,studies have examined whether the use of olfactory cues (such as pleasant ambient fragrances) can help promote green behaviours.For example, Bonini,Graffeo, Hadjichristidis and Perrotta (2015) examined when, and in what conditions, peripheral olfactory information may influence people’s willingness to pay for public goods.Specifically, the authors investigated two reforestation interventions—one concerning the National Park Adamello Brenta(which is mainly composed of pine trees) and another concerning the lemon cultivations near Lake Garda—in one of three ambient fragrance conditions:a Scots pine fragrance was diffused in the room, a lemon fragrance was diffused in the room, or no fragrance was diffused in the room.That is, each participant evaluated a single target public good in just one of the three fragrance conditions.The findings show a semantic congruence effect (but only for the least popular lemon garden public good): for this public good, WTP was higher when the lemon fragrance was dispersed in the room rather than when either no fragrance or the pine fragrance was dispersed in the room.In a subsequent study, the citizens who were given €8 to participate in the experiment, contributed €5.68 on average in favour of the lemon tree reforestation intervention when a lemon fragrance was dispersed in the air versus €4.80 when a Scots pine fragrance was dispersed in the air which, although it was evaluated as equally pleasant as the lemon fragrance, it was not semantically congruent with lemon cultivations.The role of ambient fragrance on charity has also been documented by Liljenquist, Zhong and Galinsky (2010).

    The finding that ambient fragrances can influence judgments and choices are hardly surprising for researchers studying multisensory marketing (see Turley & Milliman, 2000).

    Sony

    , for example,diffuses a fragrance of vanilla and mandarin orange in its 36 Sony Style Stores, which are boutiques showcasing Sony’s electronic goods (

    Corriere della Sera

    , October 3, 2006, p.24).Notice, however, that the results reported by Bonini and colleagues are qualitatively different from many of those reported in multisensory marketing.In their study, people are unlikely to have confused or attributed an ambient fragrance to the characteristics of the target public good (this is different, for example, to promoting apples by dispersing a fragrance of fresh apples in the air).Moreover, the study by Bonini and colleagues shows that certain characteristics that are irrelevant for a particular choice (e.g., peripheral information such as ambient fragrance) are important theoretically.Sugden writes in relation to this (commenting on the effort of “saving” the rational decision theory): “This approach seems more credible for some anomalies than for others.For example, if stated valuations are affected by salient but clearly irrelevant cues,

    it is difficult to claim that welfare is affected in a parallel way

    ” (Sugden, 2005, p.10, emphasis ours).

    Apart from olfactory contextual priming, studies have also investigated the impact of visual contextual priming.For example, Dorofeeva, Bonini and Hadjichristidis (2017) primed one group of participants with neutral images (e.g., geometric shapes) while another with images of nature (e.g., the image of a mountain).To hide the real purpose of the study,participants were instructed that their task was to rate how much they liked each image.However, the real measure of interest was the participants recycling behavior.Specifically, at the beginning of the experiment, participants were given a cookie (on a plastic plate) and a tissue paper.The main measure of interest was whether visual priming influences participants recycling behavior – i.e., whether it

    affected whether participants properly disposed of the plastic plate (plastic bin) and the tissue paper (paper bin).The results demonstrate a significant effect of visual priming.The percentage of participants that recycled the plate and the paper were about twice as high in the nature priming condition (48% for the plastic plate; 45% for the paper tissue) than in the neutral priming condition (25% for the plastic plate:25% for the tissue paper).

    Future directions

    Several of the reported studies involved laboratory experiments and examined judgments (e.g., stated willingness to contribute for a public good) rather than actual behavior (e.g., real monetary contributions).Therefore, it is unclear whether the results obtained extend to real-life situations.Thus,future research should test these interventions in the“wild,” such as through field experiments, and examine their real impact on pro-environmental behavior.Furthermore, for obvious theoretical reasons, most research has focused on a particular intervention.Future research could address whether combining interventions (default plus economic incentive; referent points plus social norms) could further aid the promotion of pro-environmental behavior.Even if the combined effect of interventions is not additive, such research could shed light into the underlying processes.Finally, some of the interventions are not readily “actionable” (Teachman et al., 2015).For example, the finding that priming participants with pictures of nature (in a computer screen) increases correct recycling practices is hard to put into practice.Therefore, future research should turn these ideas into interventions that could actually be implemented (e.g., pictures of nature near collection areas) and examine their efficacy.

    General discussion

    A plethora of behavioral findings suggests that the“constructed preference” theory provides a better account of how people evaluate public goods and make decisions about whether or not to support them(for a discussion see Lichtenstein & Slovic, 2006).Decisions about environmental public goods may be difficult for a number of reasons, which may force, in turn, people to construct their preferences online.First, citizens are frequently unfamiliar about the target good they are asked to support.Consider, a donation request from a religious institution to improve the quality of life of a previously unknown ethnic group in the Amazon forest.Second, even if citizens are familiar with the target public good, they may have difficulties in translating their preferences into numbers.For instance, an individual may clearly prefer to save a panda than to save a wild goat but at the same time may not know how to translate this preference in a specific monetary contribution.Third,although citizens may be familiar with, or have a clear preference for, particular public goods when these are evaluated separately, they may find it hard to evaluate them when these are presented together.From the construction of preference perspective, it is also easy to make sense of results that contravene standard economic theory, such as that citizens are frequently insensitive to the size of the public good.

    Therefore, the results discussed in this paper support the idea that people do not have stable preferences that are “revealed” in estimations about the value of a public good.Rather, people construct such preferences and WTP estimations in the here and now.Such evaluations are a function not only of the consequences deriving from supporting a public good (e.g., the associated costs and benefits) but also of how this evaluation is made: for example, how the consequences are mentally represented (e.g., how they are framed) and processed (e.g., whether people place more weight on affective reactions or analysis/reason).Of course, the two aspects may interact: an evaluation based on affective reactions may be favored by a given frame or a context of judgment such as when one is asked to evaluate a public good on its own, rather than jointly with another public good.

    In conclusion, the research presented herein suggests that WTP evaluations do not reflect an economic preference but rather the responders’attitude toward the good, as was suggested by Kahneman et al.(1999).The fact that the expression of the attitude is contingent on the features of the context in which a choice takes place, opens several possibilities for the architect of choice to nudge people towards greener choices and lifestyles.

    日韩三级伦理在线观看| 午夜福利影视在线免费观看| av有码第一页| 久久精品国产亚洲av天美| 中文字幕精品免费在线观看视频| 性少妇av在线| 捣出白浆h1v1| 国产又色又爽无遮挡免| 日韩一区二区三区影片| 中文字幕最新亚洲高清| 久久久a久久爽久久v久久| 五月天丁香电影| 久久热在线av| 各种免费的搞黄视频| 亚洲精品久久久久久婷婷小说| 久久精品人人爽人人爽视色| 波多野结衣av一区二区av| 亚洲精品国产av蜜桃| 久久精品国产综合久久久| 观看美女的网站| 18禁国产床啪视频网站| 国产亚洲欧美精品永久| 国产探花极品一区二区| 校园人妻丝袜中文字幕| 久久久亚洲精品成人影院| av有码第一页| 国产av一区二区精品久久| 少妇人妻精品综合一区二区| 91精品国产国语对白视频| 搡老乐熟女国产| 男女边吃奶边做爰视频| 精品国产乱码久久久久久小说| 亚洲精品乱久久久久久| 精品国产一区二区久久| 日韩av不卡免费在线播放| 人人妻人人爽人人添夜夜欢视频| 极品少妇高潮喷水抽搐| 好男人视频免费观看在线| 久久影院123| 久久精品亚洲av国产电影网| 久久鲁丝午夜福利片| 欧美在线黄色| 老鸭窝网址在线观看| 晚上一个人看的免费电影| 观看美女的网站| 国产精品欧美亚洲77777| 美女主播在线视频| 69精品国产乱码久久久| 亚洲欧美一区二区三区黑人 | av国产精品久久久久影院| 老汉色∧v一级毛片| 侵犯人妻中文字幕一二三四区| 丝袜脚勾引网站| 国产成人aa在线观看| 18禁观看日本| 黄色视频在线播放观看不卡| 亚洲,一卡二卡三卡| 有码 亚洲区| 精品人妻熟女毛片av久久网站| 一级爰片在线观看| 国产又爽黄色视频| 99久久人妻综合| 女的被弄到高潮叫床怎么办| 欧美激情高清一区二区三区 | 黄色怎么调成土黄色| 各种免费的搞黄视频| 这个男人来自地球电影免费观看 | 久久精品国产亚洲av高清一级| 日本免费在线观看一区| 婷婷色麻豆天堂久久| 亚洲av国产av综合av卡| 少妇被粗大猛烈的视频| 日本午夜av视频| 国产午夜精品一二区理论片| 欧美精品高潮呻吟av久久| 亚洲国产色片| 丝袜脚勾引网站| 女的被弄到高潮叫床怎么办| 天天躁狠狠躁夜夜躁狠狠躁| 91精品三级在线观看| 国产伦理片在线播放av一区| 老司机影院毛片| 一级,二级,三级黄色视频| 久久精品国产自在天天线| 爱豆传媒免费全集在线观看| 中国国产av一级| 午夜福利视频精品| 飞空精品影院首页| av线在线观看网站| 蜜桃在线观看..| 欧美 日韩 精品 国产| 考比视频在线观看| 另类亚洲欧美激情| 国产欧美亚洲国产| videosex国产| 又大又黄又爽视频免费| 亚洲伊人久久精品综合| 久久人人爽av亚洲精品天堂| 自拍欧美九色日韩亚洲蝌蚪91| 国产亚洲午夜精品一区二区久久| 欧美日韩一区二区视频在线观看视频在线| 亚洲在久久综合| 少妇的逼水好多| 色94色欧美一区二区| 亚洲人成电影观看| 极品人妻少妇av视频| 国产精品 欧美亚洲| 美国免费a级毛片| 啦啦啦啦在线视频资源| 秋霞在线观看毛片| 亚洲少妇的诱惑av| 国产在线视频一区二区| 在线看a的网站| 亚洲色图 男人天堂 中文字幕| 日日撸夜夜添| 91久久精品国产一区二区三区| 热re99久久国产66热| 热re99久久精品国产66热6| 久久精品国产亚洲av天美| 国产又色又爽无遮挡免| 熟女电影av网| 青草久久国产| 久久这里只有精品19| 国产日韩一区二区三区精品不卡| 久久 成人 亚洲| 国产无遮挡羞羞视频在线观看| 老女人水多毛片| 国产精品.久久久| 大话2 男鬼变身卡| 丝袜人妻中文字幕| 亚洲精品国产一区二区精华液| 欧美日韩av久久| 国产午夜精品一二区理论片| 超色免费av| 人人妻人人添人人爽欧美一区卜| 九九爱精品视频在线观看| 久久国产精品大桥未久av| 中文字幕色久视频| 麻豆乱淫一区二区| 欧美激情 高清一区二区三区| 婷婷色麻豆天堂久久| 色视频在线一区二区三区| 99久久人妻综合| 免费观看在线日韩| 欧美少妇被猛烈插入视频| 美女福利国产在线| 韩国av在线不卡| 日本黄色日本黄色录像| 亚洲欧洲国产日韩| 高清欧美精品videossex| 巨乳人妻的诱惑在线观看| av网站免费在线观看视频| 亚洲精品国产色婷婷电影| 免费看av在线观看网站| 90打野战视频偷拍视频| 国产高清国产精品国产三级| 婷婷色av中文字幕| 精品国产露脸久久av麻豆| 夫妻午夜视频| 新久久久久国产一级毛片| 久久久久久久久久久久大奶| 精品少妇内射三级| 老女人水多毛片| 亚洲一区二区三区欧美精品| 日本av手机在线免费观看| 亚洲精品国产av蜜桃| 你懂的网址亚洲精品在线观看| 欧美中文综合在线视频| 亚洲国产成人一精品久久久| 成人毛片a级毛片在线播放| av网站在线播放免费| 亚洲三区欧美一区| 夫妻性生交免费视频一级片| 国产高清国产精品国产三级| 国产亚洲精品第一综合不卡| 欧美精品一区二区免费开放| 一本大道久久a久久精品| 免费少妇av软件| 2022亚洲国产成人精品| 久久午夜福利片| 免费黄网站久久成人精品| 大话2 男鬼变身卡| 制服人妻中文乱码| 久久久久久免费高清国产稀缺| 亚洲经典国产精华液单| 成人影院久久| 精品99又大又爽又粗少妇毛片| 免费观看在线日韩| av免费在线看不卡| 亚洲人成电影观看| 日韩三级伦理在线观看| 熟女少妇亚洲综合色aaa.| 最近手机中文字幕大全| 日韩 亚洲 欧美在线| 久久精品国产a三级三级三级| 亚洲人成网站在线观看播放| 伦理电影大哥的女人| 亚洲色图 男人天堂 中文字幕| 欧美日韩视频高清一区二区三区二| 精品国产超薄肉色丝袜足j| 赤兔流量卡办理| 午夜福利网站1000一区二区三区| 成人国语在线视频| 午夜福利影视在线免费观看| 午夜精品国产一区二区电影| 看免费成人av毛片| 男女无遮挡免费网站观看| 精品99又大又爽又粗少妇毛片| 国产免费现黄频在线看| 亚洲伊人久久精品综合| 国产成人免费无遮挡视频| 亚洲国产欧美日韩在线播放| 亚洲精华国产精华液的使用体验| 久久99精品国语久久久| av国产精品久久久久影院| 18禁观看日本| 亚洲经典国产精华液单| 黄片无遮挡物在线观看| 9色porny在线观看| 午夜日韩欧美国产| 天天躁夜夜躁狠狠久久av| 国产极品天堂在线| av在线观看视频网站免费| 只有这里有精品99| 黑人欧美特级aaaaaa片| 欧美人与性动交α欧美软件| 男女午夜视频在线观看| av有码第一页| 人成视频在线观看免费观看| 国产男人的电影天堂91| 在现免费观看毛片| 国产亚洲精品第一综合不卡| 在线天堂最新版资源| 日韩一卡2卡3卡4卡2021年| 王馨瑶露胸无遮挡在线观看| 97在线人人人人妻| 国产熟女欧美一区二区| 色婷婷av一区二区三区视频| 中文字幕精品免费在线观看视频| 久久国产精品男人的天堂亚洲| 亚洲精品aⅴ在线观看| 伦理电影免费视频| 久久精品夜色国产| 国产亚洲精品第一综合不卡| 午夜福利在线免费观看网站| 亚洲av成人精品一二三区| 成人18禁高潮啪啪吃奶动态图| 欧美日韩亚洲高清精品| 欧美精品人与动牲交sv欧美| 高清欧美精品videossex| 久久鲁丝午夜福利片| 97在线视频观看| videos熟女内射| 午夜av观看不卡| 女性被躁到高潮视频| 日本黄色日本黄色录像| av一本久久久久| 国产一区有黄有色的免费视频| 欧美日韩成人在线一区二区| 下体分泌物呈黄色| 满18在线观看网站| 春色校园在线视频观看| 一本一本久久a久久精品综合妖精 国产伦在线观看视频一区 | 精品酒店卫生间| 国产精品秋霞免费鲁丝片| 少妇猛男粗大的猛烈进出视频| 三上悠亚av全集在线观看| 成人亚洲精品一区在线观看| av免费在线看不卡| 在现免费观看毛片| 亚洲伊人色综图| 国产精品av久久久久免费| 日韩精品有码人妻一区| 国产av国产精品国产| 成年av动漫网址| 成年美女黄网站色视频大全免费| 日本猛色少妇xxxxx猛交久久| 我要看黄色一级片免费的| 97在线人人人人妻| 99精国产麻豆久久婷婷| 性少妇av在线| 一区二区三区乱码不卡18| 国产成人精品一,二区| 女人久久www免费人成看片| 精品国产乱码久久久久久男人| 美女主播在线视频| 人人澡人人妻人| 韩国av在线不卡| 久久亚洲国产成人精品v| 纵有疾风起免费观看全集完整版| 日韩制服骚丝袜av| 高清不卡的av网站| 婷婷色av中文字幕| 国产毛片在线视频| 亚洲精品久久久久久婷婷小说| 欧美日韩亚洲国产一区二区在线观看 | 宅男免费午夜| 制服诱惑二区| 午夜福利视频精品| 高清在线视频一区二区三区| 伊人亚洲综合成人网| 国产一区二区在线观看av| 久久午夜福利片| 18禁动态无遮挡网站| 女性生殖器流出的白浆| 亚洲av国产av综合av卡| 国产激情久久老熟女| 秋霞在线观看毛片| 波多野结衣av一区二区av| 免费看不卡的av| 丝袜美腿诱惑在线| 精品国产乱码久久久久久小说| 国产高清国产精品国产三级| 亚洲婷婷狠狠爱综合网| 免费黄色在线免费观看| 日韩视频在线欧美| 男的添女的下面高潮视频| 26uuu在线亚洲综合色| 色视频在线一区二区三区| 又黄又粗又硬又大视频| 成人亚洲欧美一区二区av| 看非洲黑人一级黄片| 国产福利在线免费观看视频| 少妇人妻久久综合中文| 丝袜脚勾引网站| 久久鲁丝午夜福利片| 欧美精品国产亚洲| 精品久久久精品久久久| 1024香蕉在线观看| 国产成人精品久久二区二区91 | 蜜桃在线观看..| 看非洲黑人一级黄片| 日韩免费高清中文字幕av| 人妻 亚洲 视频| 18在线观看网站| 一本久久精品| 美女国产高潮福利片在线看| 欧美在线黄色| av免费观看日本| 日本欧美国产在线视频| 99国产精品免费福利视频| 亚洲精品乱久久久久久| 黄网站色视频无遮挡免费观看| 久久久久久久久久久免费av| 七月丁香在线播放| 卡戴珊不雅视频在线播放| 18禁观看日本| 香蕉丝袜av| 亚洲av福利一区| 午夜激情av网站| 五月开心婷婷网| 一级片'在线观看视频| 亚洲精品国产av蜜桃| 久久精品国产亚洲av高清一级| 少妇的逼水好多| 看非洲黑人一级黄片| 中文乱码字字幕精品一区二区三区| 国产精品不卡视频一区二区| 五月伊人婷婷丁香| 下体分泌物呈黄色| 日韩熟女老妇一区二区性免费视频| 熟女少妇亚洲综合色aaa.| 午夜精品国产一区二区电影| 最近最新中文字幕大全免费视频 | 天堂中文最新版在线下载| 国产综合精华液| 97在线人人人人妻| 国产精品偷伦视频观看了| 一本久久精品| 免费看不卡的av| 99久久中文字幕三级久久日本| 少妇熟女欧美另类| 亚洲av日韩在线播放| 一本久久精品| 国产福利在线免费观看视频| a 毛片基地| 母亲3免费完整高清在线观看 | 久久久久久久久久人人人人人人| 国产一区二区 视频在线| 尾随美女入室| 日本vs欧美在线观看视频| 男人爽女人下面视频在线观看| 91精品三级在线观看| 国产精品三级大全| 伊人久久大香线蕉亚洲五| 天天操日日干夜夜撸| 日韩成人av中文字幕在线观看| videos熟女内射| 最新的欧美精品一区二区| 午夜日韩欧美国产| 亚洲视频免费观看视频| 亚洲精品乱久久久久久| 亚洲精品在线美女| 国产熟女欧美一区二区| 人人澡人人妻人| 热99久久久久精品小说推荐| 十分钟在线观看高清视频www| 久久久久久免费高清国产稀缺| 欧美日韩综合久久久久久| 啦啦啦在线观看免费高清www| 999精品在线视频| 欧美精品人与动牲交sv欧美| 一级毛片我不卡| 91精品三级在线观看| 免费久久久久久久精品成人欧美视频| 亚洲图色成人| 中文欧美无线码| 不卡av一区二区三区| 国产成人一区二区在线| 少妇的丰满在线观看| 麻豆精品久久久久久蜜桃| 成人毛片60女人毛片免费| 久久精品久久精品一区二区三区| 久热这里只有精品99| 美女国产视频在线观看| 午夜影院在线不卡| √禁漫天堂资源中文www| 精品一区二区三卡| 欧美另类一区| 青春草视频在线免费观看| 久久免费观看电影| 国产一区二区三区av在线| 国产在视频线精品| 99re6热这里在线精品视频| 色吧在线观看| 亚洲 欧美一区二区三区| 蜜桃国产av成人99| 日韩人妻精品一区2区三区| 丰满少妇做爰视频| 国产伦理片在线播放av一区| 久久久国产一区二区| 新久久久久国产一级毛片| 欧美日韩精品成人综合77777| 国产黄色视频一区二区在线观看| 一级爰片在线观看| 久久鲁丝午夜福利片| 国产一区亚洲一区在线观看| 一区二区三区激情视频| 日本-黄色视频高清免费观看| 丰满乱子伦码专区| 波多野结衣av一区二区av| 欧美人与性动交α欧美精品济南到 | 午夜激情久久久久久久| 中文字幕制服av| 久久99蜜桃精品久久| a级毛片黄视频| 熟女电影av网| 亚洲色图综合在线观看| 亚洲精品一二三| 国产激情久久老熟女| 国产亚洲av片在线观看秒播厂| 欧美bdsm另类| 最近的中文字幕免费完整| 成人免费观看视频高清| 午夜免费鲁丝| 亚洲欧美成人精品一区二区| 伦理电影免费视频| 午夜免费观看性视频| 777米奇影视久久| 国产精品久久久av美女十八| 超色免费av| 亚洲五月色婷婷综合| 精品国产露脸久久av麻豆| 亚洲,一卡二卡三卡| 日韩,欧美,国产一区二区三区| 亚洲av福利一区| 一区二区日韩欧美中文字幕| 黄片播放在线免费| 国产一区二区激情短视频 | 欧美最新免费一区二区三区| 亚洲四区av| 亚洲精品aⅴ在线观看| 日韩 亚洲 欧美在线| 久久99蜜桃精品久久| 99久久人妻综合| 久久久国产一区二区| 亚洲第一青青草原| 国产精品久久久久久av不卡| 深夜精品福利| 黑人猛操日本美女一级片| 秋霞伦理黄片| 自拍欧美九色日韩亚洲蝌蚪91| 精品亚洲成国产av| 性少妇av在线| 国产精品蜜桃在线观看| 日韩av不卡免费在线播放| 老司机影院成人| 欧美激情高清一区二区三区 | av国产精品久久久久影院| 精品少妇内射三级| 99国产精品免费福利视频| 中文字幕色久视频| 一个人免费看片子| 少妇被粗大猛烈的视频| 亚洲三区欧美一区| 国产精品偷伦视频观看了| 伊人久久大香线蕉亚洲五| 亚洲av福利一区| 亚洲欧美成人精品一区二区| 国产成人免费无遮挡视频| 在线天堂最新版资源| 国产精品99久久99久久久不卡 | xxx大片免费视频| 日韩欧美一区视频在线观看| 成人漫画全彩无遮挡| www.av在线官网国产| 春色校园在线视频观看| 一区二区三区精品91| 亚洲精品中文字幕在线视频| 搡女人真爽免费视频火全软件| 欧美日韩亚洲高清精品| 人人妻人人澡人人看| av在线老鸭窝| 久久人人爽av亚洲精品天堂| 精品国产露脸久久av麻豆| 麻豆乱淫一区二区| 日韩制服骚丝袜av| 亚洲人成网站在线观看播放| 丝袜美足系列| 一级,二级,三级黄色视频| 欧美日韩亚洲高清精品| 大片电影免费在线观看免费| 99国产精品免费福利视频| 免费在线观看视频国产中文字幕亚洲 | 亚洲,一卡二卡三卡| 寂寞人妻少妇视频99o| 热re99久久精品国产66热6| 中文字幕人妻熟女乱码| 男人添女人高潮全过程视频| 久久99热这里只频精品6学生| 成年美女黄网站色视频大全免费| 国产无遮挡羞羞视频在线观看| 色吧在线观看| 国产精品不卡视频一区二区| 人妻人人澡人人爽人人| 男的添女的下面高潮视频| 中文字幕亚洲精品专区| 欧美精品国产亚洲| 久久久久国产网址| av不卡在线播放| 午夜av观看不卡| 国产黄色视频一区二区在线观看| 国产麻豆69| 久久婷婷青草| 国产精品久久久久久av不卡| 1024视频免费在线观看| 精品亚洲乱码少妇综合久久| 国产视频首页在线观看| 丝袜美腿诱惑在线| 亚洲精品在线美女| 中文精品一卡2卡3卡4更新| 在线天堂中文资源库| 亚洲国产精品成人久久小说| 亚洲美女视频黄频| 久久久欧美国产精品| 性色avwww在线观看| 午夜日本视频在线| 99久久人妻综合| 在线观看国产h片| 中文字幕另类日韩欧美亚洲嫩草| 蜜桃国产av成人99| 亚洲精品国产一区二区精华液| 成人免费观看视频高清| 精品少妇一区二区三区视频日本电影 | 电影成人av| 三上悠亚av全集在线观看| 久久久国产一区二区| 日韩熟女老妇一区二区性免费视频| 少妇 在线观看| 欧美日韩精品成人综合77777| 97在线人人人人妻| 熟女少妇亚洲综合色aaa.| 亚洲第一青青草原| 最近中文字幕高清免费大全6| 老女人水多毛片| 99热国产这里只有精品6| 熟妇人妻不卡中文字幕| 成人国产av品久久久| 制服人妻中文乱码| 欧美日本中文国产一区发布| 亚洲成人手机| 精品国产露脸久久av麻豆| 久久久久精品性色| 国产黄色免费在线视频| 久久久久久久大尺度免费视频| 少妇人妻 视频| 一级爰片在线观看| 国产亚洲午夜精品一区二区久久| 国产不卡av网站在线观看| 国产av国产精品国产| 精品国产露脸久久av麻豆| 黄色视频在线播放观看不卡| 91国产中文字幕| 男人舔女人的私密视频| 欧美精品国产亚洲| 日韩在线高清观看一区二区三区| 观看美女的网站| 美女脱内裤让男人舔精品视频| 美女国产高潮福利片在线看| 香蕉国产在线看| 亚洲少妇的诱惑av| 欧美国产精品一级二级三级| 色网站视频免费| 婷婷成人精品国产| 久久久精品国产亚洲av高清涩受| 亚洲,欧美精品.| 我要看黄色一级片免费的| 亚洲美女黄色视频免费看| 国产亚洲精品第一综合不卡| 久久97久久精品| 国产极品天堂在线| 精品一区二区三卡| videossex国产| 国产熟女午夜一区二区三区| 80岁老熟妇乱子伦牲交|